The 5 E's of Economics

[NOTE: This lecture, or instructor note, is fairly long. Most of the other instructor lectures will be significantly shorter.]

I. What Is Economics?

Just what is the study of economics? A common "textbook-like" definition might be:

Economics is the study of how we choose to use limited resources to obtain the maximum satisfaction of unlimited human wants

This definition has four parts that we need to discuss:

  1. the "study of" economics
  2. choice
  3. scarcity
  4. maximizing satisfaction

A definition of "economics" that I used when I first taught is:


( NOTE: I am Mark and soon after I moved to Illinois I bought a house in Wonder Lake in McHenry County. Wonder Lake is a nice lake, private, but we didn't own a boat.)

My definition highlights an important component of economics: SCARCITY. The reason why I didn't have a boat, or the reason why you don't have everything that you want is because of SCARCITY.

The term "scarcity" has a slightly different definition in an economics class than it does in the "real" world.

NOTE: Many words have different meanings in an economics class than the definition that you may already know. For example, let's take the word DEMAND. If I ask you "What happens to the demand for boats when the price of boats goes up?"

If the price of boats goes up, then demand for boats goes . . . . . .

 

 

NO! THE DEMAND DOES NOT GO DOWN. The quantity demanded goes down, but not demand itself. BECAUSE ECONOMISTS HAVE A DIFFERENT DEFINITION FOR DEMAND. We'll talk more about that later.

Another example is the word INVESTMENT. In an economics class the term "investment" does NOT mean the stock market, money markets. or mutual funds. We will have to call such things "financial investments" because the term investment has a different meaning in economics.

So back to the term SCARCITY. Scarcity does not mean that only a little of something is available. For example, I grew up in northeastern Minnesota . About 30 miles away from my hometown was the town of Erskine, Minnesota. Just outside of town a certain type of rock exists that occurs nowhere else in the world. They have named it "Erskinite". Erskinite is only found near Erskine, Minnesota and only a little of it has ever been found. BUT there is plenty of ERSKINITE and it IS NOT SCARCE -- WHY? - - -

Because nobody wants it. For there to be scarcity things must be LIMITED and WANTED.

Goods and services are scarce. These are the things that we want. Goods are tangible things that satisfy our wants (like boats, computers, cars, etc.), services are intangible things that satisfy our wants (like the services of an accountant, or a dentist, or a lawyer).

This brings us to another important principle in economics.

After teaching economics for a year or so, I bought a boat. Since I defined economics as the study of why I didn't have a boat - I had a problem. But then I simply changed my definition slightly. Now economics is: the study of why Mark doesn't have a . . a . . .a what?

This brings us to that second principle: economists assume that humans have UNLIMITED WANTS. Once I got a boat, I wanted a bigger boat. After getting a bigger boat I wanted a sailboat. then a row boat, and . . . and the list goes on and on. (I now own 5 boats and I want a jetski.) Do we ever have EVERYTHING that we could ever want?

Since human wants are unlimited, and resources used to satisfy those wants are limited - there is scarcity. Even in the US, one of the richest countries in the world, there is scarcity -- if we use our new definition of SCARCITY. There is always scarcity, because human wants are unlimited.

This then brings use to a third important idea: Because of scarcity we MUST MAKE CHOICES. Some economists call this the "economizing problem". We can't have everything that we want so we have to choose.

This is what economics is really all about - MAKING CHOICES. Because of scarcity we as individuals, and our society as a whole, must make choices. Our goal is to reduce scarcity as much as we can. Another way to say this is that we want to get the MAXIMUM SATISFACTION possible out of our limited resources. We don't want to make just any choice, we want to make the BEST choice.

There are three, and only three, options(choices) for society to deal with scarcity, and all societies must deal with scarcity because there are limited resources and unlimited wants.

Those three options are:

  1. economic growth
  2. reduce our wants, and
  3. use our existing resources wisely (Don't waste the few resources that we do have.)

 

Let's look at each of these briefly.

Economic Growth (the first "E")

Let's define Economic Growth as an increase in the ABILITY to produce goods and services. This is not the way the term is normally defined. Later this semester we'll discuss the various definitions of Economic Growth, but here we'll use this more fundamental definition:

Economic Growth is an increase in the ABILITY to produce goods and services.

This means we are ABLE to produce more, but it doesn't necessarily mean we do produce more. More on this later.

This type of Economic Growth is caused by:

a) more resources
b) better resources
c) better technology

If we only had more resources we could produce more goods and services and satisfy more of our wants. This will reduce scarcity and give us more satisfaction (more good and services). All societies therefore try to achieve economic growth.

Reducing Wants

A second way for a society to handle scarcity is to reduce its wants. If we just didn't want so much then there would be less scarcity. For example we know that gasoline is scarce. (Can you get all that you want for the price you want? If you have to pay a price for something, then it is scarce.) Space on our roads is also often very scarce. Let's say that the president of the United States decides to do something about these problems by initiating a new program called: SHARE A CAR WITH YOUR NEIGHBOR. It includes a law that says there can only be ONE CAR FOR EVERY TWO FAMILIES. This would reduce the scarcity of gasoline and space on our roadways, but . . . . let's impeach that president!!!

The option of REDUCING WANTS is one of the options that societies have for dealing with scarcity, but it is not a very good option. Maybe during war time, if our president asks us to "share a car with our neighbor", we would. But it is not a long-term solution to the problem of scarcity that most of us would accept. Although it is an option that we should keep in mind.

That brings us to the third option for dealing with scarcity (and to the remaining 4 "E's" of economics.)

Using our existing resources wisely = maximizing satisfaction

Societies can reduce scarcity not just by (1) getting more resources, better resources, or better technology (i.e. ECONOMIC GROWTH), or by (2) REDUCING ITS WANTS, but also by (3) USING ITS EXISTING RESOURCES WISELY

There are four ways that societies can use their EXISTING resources to reduce scarcity. I call these the 4 Es of economics - four ways to use our existing resources to reduce scarcity and obtain the maximum satisfaction possible. The fifth E (economic growth) also reduces scarcity and gives us more satisfaction but it does it by using ADDITIONAL resources. Societies will try to achieve all 5 Es of economics.

The four ways that societies can use their EXISTING resources to reduce scarcity are:

  1. Productive Efficiency
  2. Allocative Efficiency
  3. Full Employment, and
  4. Equity

 

Maximizing Satisfaction --
[Four More Es:
Efficiency, Efficiency, Equity, Employment]

Let's discuss each of these individually keeping in mind

  1. their definition,
  2. examples of each, and most importantly
  3. how do they reduce scarcity and help society achieve the MAXIMUM SATISFACTION from their available resources?

PRODUCTIVE EFFICIENCY

Productive efficiency can be defined as, or achieved by, producing at a minimum cost

By producing at a minimum cost, FEWER RESOURCES are used and MORE can be produced. This reduces scarcity and gives us more satisfaction from our existing resources.

We can produce at a minimum cost and achieve productive efficiency by:

a. not using more resources than necessary
b. using resources where they are best suited
c. using appropriate technology

Let's look at each of these individually using some examples. REMEMBER our goal is to understand how they reduce scarcity and help society achieve the maximum satisfaction possible. This is the goal of economics. You must keep this goal in mind as we go through these examples.

not using more resources than necessary

How does this MAXIMIZE SOCIETY'S SATISFACTION?

If businesses use extra resources that they do not need, then these resources are wasted. Since we know that resources are limited and human wants are unlimited, let's not waste any of the few resources that we do have. By not using more resources than necessary, we free up resources that can be used somewhere else and we PRODUCE MORE.

Examples:

(a) Janitors at Harper

Let's assume that Harper College employs 50 janitors to clean its buildings and that's enough to do a good job. If Harper then hired 25 more janitors this would be wasteful. Even though they could probably find something to do to keep busy, they aren't needed. Fifty janitors can do the job. So society would be better off if Harper did NOT employ these additional janitors so that they could go get a job somewhere else (like maybe at a boat factory) where they would produce more for society. It would be productively inefficient to employ 75 janitors at Harper. Harper's costs will be higher (productive inefficiency) and society's output would be lower (less satisfaction).

(b) Grocery stores: USSR

Several years ago, one of my students gave me this example. She had visited Moscow when the communist Soviet Union still existed. She said that she was surprised when she entered a grocery store and saw four employees at every cash register! What a waste of labor resources. In the US we find one, or two, workers at a checkout stand and only a few will be open. In Moscow ALL stands were open with four employees each. This is productively inefficient. Their costs are higher and since labor is being wasted, they will produce less. They are not achieving the maximum satisfaction possible from their limited resources (productive inefficiency).

(c) Motorola/Sears/AT&T/etc. lay off 1,000s of workers

Take a brief look at one or a few of the following news articles. (When you click on the link they should appear in a new browser window.)

Are these layoffs good for society?

If each company was able to continue producing the same amount of output after laying off thousands of workers then they must have been productively inefficient before the layoffs. So, if it would be good for Harper to only employ 50 janitors (and layoff the extra 25) or if it would be good for the grocery stores in the Soviet Union to lay off some of their employees, THEN THESE LAYOFFS ARE GOOD FOR SOCIETY.

I realize that this may be a bit controversial. If you have questions let's discuss them in class.

Keep in mind the GOAL: reducing scarcity and achieving the maximum satisfaction possible from our limited resources. If these companies can still produce the same amount of output with thousands fewer employees, by laying them off they become available to work somewhere else producing MORE for society.

BUT, will they find another job? These articles indicate that in today's economy they probably will:

WHAT IF THEY DON'T FIND A JOB? Would it be better for society to have them stay at companies where they are not needed or to be unemployed collecting unemployment compensation or welfare?

I would consider the possibility that it would it be BETTER for society to have them be unemployed collecting unemployment compensation or welfare. That way we know they are AVAILABLE for any new boat companies that may want to build a new factory.

Not all layoffs are good for society. See: lay-offs.htm

using resources where they are best suited

The second way to produce at a minimum cost and achieve productive efficiency is to use resources where they are best suited.

How does this MAXIMIZE SOCIETY'S SATISFACTION?

If businesses use resources where they are best suited then MORE can be produced from the same amount of resources.

Examples:

(a) secretaries / truck drivers

Let's say I own a company which employs secretaries and truck drivers. Normally the secretaries type letters and the truck drivers drive trucks. One day I decide to try something new . I had the secretaries drive the trucks and the truck drivers type letters.

What happened to the COST per load delivered or the COST per letter typed? Hopefully you were thinking "they went up." Therefore we are not producing at a minimum cost and we are productively inefficient. Furthermore, and most importantly, LESS WILL BE PRODUCED.

Therefore, to be productively efficient and achieve the maximum satisfaction possible from our existing resources we must use resources where they are best suited.

(b) doctors/engineers

Doctors should work in the hospitals and engineers should build the bridges. This would be productively efficient. More bridges will be built and more lives saved . It would be productively inefficient (i.e. more costly) to have engineers work in the hospitals and doctors build the bridges. Fewer bridges would be built and fewer lives saved. This would be productively inefficient - a waste of existing resources.

(c) Illinois-corn/Alabama-cotton - another example, but with something new

Illinois has resources (weather, machinery, soil, etc.) better suited to grow corn, whereas Alabama has resources better suited to grow cotton. So it makes sense for Illinois to grow corn and for Alabama to grow cotton since this way we get more corn and more cotton from the same amount of resources. This is productively efficient. But there is just one problem. In Illinois we have a lot to eat (corn) but no clothes (cotton). And in Alabama they have cotton clothing, but they are staving. So what do we do?

We exchange or trade. We in Illinois sell corn to those in Alabama and they sell cotton to us.

If we didn't trade then we would have to grow both corn and cotton and Alabama would have do the same. The result would be LESS CORN and LESS COTTON being produced. from the same resources we would have fewer goods because we are not using resources where they are best suited - i.e. productive inefficiency.

(d) North Dakota-potatoes / Honduras-sugar

North Dakota has resources suited to growing potatoes (cold climate, good soil, etc.). Honduras, in Central America, has resources suited to growing sugar, or sugar cane (hot wet climate, poorer soils, etc.). So it is productively efficient to grow potatoes in North Dakota and to grow sugar in Honduras. Costs are lower, and more importantly, more can be grown with the existing resources. this helps society get the maximum satisfaction possible from its existing resources.

Why, then, do they grow sugar (sugar beets) in North Dakota? The sugar that we get from sugar beets is very expensive. Why do we grow sugar beets in North Dakota when we can get cheap, high quality, sugar from Honduras?

The answer has to do with trade. There is free trade between Illinois and Alabama. Free trade means that the government does not try to restrict trade with taxes or other barriers. Therefore, Alabama and Illinois can use their resources where they are best suited and achieve productive efficiency, i.e. they produce more with the resources available.

But there are trade restrictions on sugar between the US and Honduras. This, then, encourages the farmers to be productively inefficient. The barriers to free trade results in higher prices and this encourages North Dakota farmers to grow sugar resulting in productive inefficiency and LESS BEING PRODUCED.

(e) free trade

Free trade, then, is a necessary condition to achieve productive efficiency since it allows resources to be used where they are best suited - regardless of the state, or the country.

(f) discrimination

Economists have a slightly different view of discrimination. They would ask, "How does discrimination affect the quantity of boats (and everything else) that are produced with the resources available?" Since discrimination is by definition NOT USING RESOURCES WHERE THEY ARE BEST SUITED, it results in higher costs and less output - or productive inefficiency.

using appropriate technology

The third way to produce at a minimum cost and achieve productive efficiency is to use the appropriate technology. By "appropriate" we mean the technology that minimizes the costs. Sometimes this is termed the "best "technology. But I prefer "appropriate" because "best" my infer "high tech" or computer technology. But the most up-to-date technology is not always the most appropriate (lowest cost).

How does this MAXIMIZE SOCIETY'S SATISFACTION?

By using the technology that minimizes costs, it minimizes the amount of resources used, since it is the resources that make up the costs of production.

Examples:

(a) farming: US / Kenya

For example, in the US farmers use tractors to plow their fields, whereas in the country of Kenya (in East Africa) most field are plowed by hand. It could be argued that both farmers ARE being productively efficient. The cheapest way to plow in the US is my using a $100,000 tractor. In Kenya, tractors, fuel, repairs, etc., are very expensive and labor is relatively inexpensive, so it makes economic sense to plow by hand.

(b) farming: tractors / helicopter

Why don't US farmers use "modern" technology and plow their fields with helicopters and laser beams (sort of like the Jetsons)? The answer is easy, it would be too costly. There are cheaper, and more productively efficient, ways to get the job done. 

Allocative Efficiency

The second way to use our existing resources to maximize society's satisfaction is allocative efficiency.

Allocative efficiency is using our limited resources to produce:

  • THE RIGHT MIX OF GOODS
  • MORE OF WHAT PEOPLE WANT
  • LESS OF WHAT PEOPLE DON'T WANT

How does this MAXIMIZE SOCIETY'S SATISFACTION and REDUCE SCARCITY?

If we want to achieve the maximum satisfaction possible from our limited resources, we not only have to be productively efficient (use as few resources as possible, use our resources where they are best suited, and use the appropriate technology), BUT WE ALSO HAVE TO PRODUCE THE RIGHT GOODS AND SERVICES. It would be a waste of our limited resources to produce a lot of things that we don't want and few of the things that we do want.

For example:

a. steel: horseshoes or cars

It would be a waste of our limited supply of steel to produce billions of horseshoes that nobody wants and only a few cars that people do want. This would be allocatively inefficient.

b. crude oil: gasoline or kerosene

People want more gasoline and very little kerosene. Therefore to use our resources wisely, we should use our crude oil to produce more gasoline and less kerosene.

c. small cars or SUVs

As consumer tastes have moved away from small cars to large Sport Utility Vehicles, an allocatively efficient society would use its resources to produce more SUVs and fewer small cars.

Allocative INefficiency occurs when we use our limited resources to produce TOO MUCH or TOO LITTLE. This results in surpluses and shortages.

How does allocative inefficiency affect scarcity and our attempt to maximize our satisfaction?

Whenever we produce too much (surplus) or too little (shortage) we are allocatively inefficient. We are NOT using our resources in a way that would achieve the maximum satisfaction possible.

Examples of allocative inefficiency:

(1) US agriculture producing mountains of unwanted grain

US (and European) farmers used to produce mountains of grain that they couldn't sell. WHY? Pizza Hut doesn't produce piles of pizza that they cannot sell. Homebuilders do not build hundreds of homes that they cannot sell. Why did US grow more grain than they knew they could sell?

The answer is - the government. The US government would buy the surplus grain form the farmers. This encouraged them to plant even more. The allocative inefficiency here is not the mountains of grain that nobody wants, but rather the loss of the resources farmers used to grow that grain. Labor, land, energy, chemicals, machinery, etc. was wasted producing something that society didn't want. The real loss are the products that we COULD HAVE HAD if farmers hadn't used so many resources producing excess grain. This is allocative inefficiency and it reduces the satisfaction that society receives from its resources. (NOTE: changes in government policy have reduced the amount of excess grain being produced.)

Long lines in Poland

Prior to 1989 when communism in Eastern Europe collapsed, Poland and other countries had severe shortages of consumer products resulting in long lines (queues). This is a good example of allocative inefficiency. Severe shortages reduces society's satisfaction.

(3) Super Bowl tickets (another example which something new)

There is a shortage of Super Bowl tickets. Hundreds of thousands of fans want to attend the game but only about 80,000 seats are available. This is allocative inefficiency. WHAT CAN BE DONE?

Build a bigger stadium? Play a 2 out of 3 (or 4 out of 7) series? OR - why not simply raise the price? The price of a regular Super Bowl ticket is around $200. At this low price, hundreds of thousands of people want to go. But what if the price was raised to $1000 or $2000, or to whatever price will result in only 80,000 tickets being sold. If they raise the price, there will be no shortage. SHORTAGES ARE CAUSED BY A PRICE THAT IS TOO LOW. This results in allocative inefficiency and less satisfaction for society.

(4) Natural disasters: "price-gouging"

Let's try another example to illustrate the importance of getting the price right to achieve allocative efficiency. After hurricane Hugo struck Florida a few years ago the price of plywood, water, hotel rooms, and many other things increased dramatically. Were these price increases BAD for the people living in Florida?

 

 

NO!!!!

 

 

This may seem controversial to many of you, but let me explain and I think you will agree with me.

After Hurricane Hugo, the people of Florida did not have all the plywood that they wanted, or needed. This is allocative inefficiency. To help them we would want two things to occur: (1) more plywood should be shipped to Florida, and (2) the people of Florida should try to conserve the plywood that they do have. This is good for the people in Florida.

Let's say that the price of plywood increased from $15 a sheet to $60 a sheet. WHAT HAPPENS?

Well, people standing in line to buy plywood to fix their walls, their decks, and their doghouses, will buy less and maybe decide to only fix their walls now, i.e. they conserve.

ALSO, maybe somebody sitting in the back of their pickup truck drinking beer on a Friday night in Chicago will hear a news report on the high price of plywood in Florida. And they may start to calculate: 100 sheets that would fit in the back of the pickup would cost, in Chicago, $1500 (100 sheets times $15 a sheet). If they drove to Florida they could sell the sheets for $6000 (100 sheets times $60 a sheet). This is a profit of $4500 in one weekend! Trucks full of plywood would be heading for Florida from all parts of the country. This is good for the people in Florida.

Now, let's say that the government of Florida wants to "help" its citizens by preventing this "price-gouging" - higher prices after a natural disaster. So they pass a law making price-gouging illegal. Let's assume that if you sell plywood for more than $15 a sheet you will be arrested. (See links below.) WHAT IS GOING TO HAPPEN? Does this Law help the people in Florida who need plywood?

First, if the people in all those pickup trucks full of plywood hear of this anti-price-gouging law, they will turn right around and drive home. This is bad for the people of Florida.

Also, those people standing at the front of the lines at the lumber yards, seeing that the price is still only $15 a sheet, will buy extra to repair their decks and fix their doghouses. This is bad for the people of Florida.

The result of the anti-price-gouging law is a SHORTAGE. A shortage CREATED by the law, not by the hurricane.

When the price of plywood rises to $60 a sheet after a hurricane it is allocatively efficient and GOOD for the people of Florida. They will CONSERVE the plywood that they have and MORE will be shipped in. This is good. Do you agree?

Oftentimes students say, "what about the poor people who can't afford the higher prices?" Will the anti-price-gouging laws help them?

NO, because there will be a shortage. This means NO PLYWOOD is available for anyone (unless they just happen to be at the front of the line).

There are better ways to help the poor. This is especially true if we can agree that the laws keeping the prices down actually hurt the poor by creating a shortage. The government could give the poor money, or haul in more plywood - but a law that keeps prices low hurts all.

I realize that this may be a bit controversial. If you have questions let's discuss them on our discussion forum. (When you click on the link it should appear in a new browser window.)

Articles on "price-gouging" in Florida:

(5) food price controls

The government-created low prices in Florida after a hurricane CREATED A SHORTAGE. What if a government keeps food prices too low? What do you call a shortage of food? -- FAMINE! Millions of people have been killed by governments that have lowered food prices creating a famine. The purpose of keeping food prices low was to help the poor and the hungry. The effects of keeping food prices low is famine. Two things happen when governments lower food prices: (1) farmers make less so they work less and grow less, and (2) since prices are low those who do find food buy more. the result is a shortage.

(6) gasoline

Different government policies concerning gasoline prices have had different effects.

(a) W.W.II

During World War II, the US government kept the price of gasoline down. This created a shortage. To handle the shortage they had to issue ration coupons. If you wanted to buy gas, you first needed a coupon. The government created the shortage. The government created allocative inefficiency.

(b) 1970s: Arab oil embargo

In the 1970s, Israel attacked its Arab neighbors and the US supported Israel. In response, the Arab oil producers refused to sell oil tot he US. This would have caused the price of gasoline to increase greatly, but President Nixon prevented the price from rising. This created a shortage. Gas stations had long lines (queues). Some would only sell gasoline on certain days or limit a purchase to 5 gallons. The government created the shortage. The government created allocative inefficiency.

(c) during Gulf War

In the early 1990's the government of Iraq invaded the country of Kuwait disrupting oil exports from the Persian Gulf. But there was no shortage of gasoline! If you wanted to buy gas you just had to drive to a gas station and fill 'er up. Why wasn't there a shortage of gasoline this time? Because the government allowed the market to work and the price increased. As a result two things happened: (1) gasoline producers did all they could to produce more gasoline, and (2) drivers conserved, carpooled, and drove less. Hence, NO SHORTAGE. This was allocatively efficient.

WHAT CAN BE DONE to achieve allocative efficiency?

In a market economy, or pure capitalism, the price will adjust to achieve allocative efficiency. Inefficiency occurs when the government interferes or if one or a few firms have control over the market.

Equity

The third way to use our existing resources to achieve the maximum satisfaction possible is equity.

Equity is a "fair" distribution of income, or goods and services. (NOTE: this is not the same definition used by accountants.) One problem with this definition is agreeing on what "fair" means.

Fair does not mean "equal". Would an equal distribution of income be good for society? Would it be good if doctors were paid the same as janitors? Probably not. If we paid doctors the same as janitors we would have few doctors, and the would not put in the time needed to learn medicine.

We know that equity is good for society (it is one of the five Es). So equitable cannot mean the same as equal. But we can't measure "fairness". This is a problem for economists. But we can DESCRIBE the actual distribution of income and I will also try to explain how equity does help society achieve the maximum satisfaction possible from its limited resources.

The Distribution of Income.

When economists describe the distribution of income they usually divide the population into groups of equal sizes (usually five called quintiles) according to their income levels. In the first quintile the put the poorest fifth (20%) of the population. In the fifth quintile they put the richest twenty percent. and they divide the remainder into the other three groups according to their incomes.

For data on the distribution of income in the US see: http://www.census.gov/ftp/pub/hhes/income/histinc/h02.html

For 1998 the US distribution of income was:

Lowest Fifth
Second Fifth
Third Fifth
Fourth Fifth
Highest Fifth
Top 5 %
3.6
9.0
15.0
23.2
49.2
21.4

Comments (discussion forum) ?

How does equity help society achieve the maximum possible satisfaction from its limited resources?

President Clinton example

Since it is difficult for us to agree on a definition of "fairness", let me see if I can come up with an extreme example on which we can all agree. What if President Clinton owned everything? I mean EVERYTHING - all the land, all the buildings, all the food, all the clothes all the cars, -- everything in the country. Therefore, the rest of us own nothing. We are homeless, starving, and naked. Not a pretty picture, but can we all agree that this is not fair (not equitable)?

Now, let's say that President Clinton gives us each a pair of pants. We should be able to agree that this is more fair, more equitable, right? So what happens to society's satisfaction? By "society" I mean all of us AND President Clinton. We are more satisfied since each of us has a pair of pant., but President Clinton is less satisfied because he has 260 million fewer pairs of pants.

So what happens to society's TOTAL satisfaction? It depends on HOW MUCH happier we are and HOW MUCH less happy President Clinton is. This brings us to the Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility. Utility is the reason we consume a goods or services. You might call it satisfaction. I get satisfaction (utility) when I drive my boat. I get utility (satisfaction?) when I go to the dentist. "Marginal" means EXTRA or ADDITIONAL.

According to the law of diminishing marginal utility the EXTRA (not the total) utility diminishes for each additional unit consumed. The first time I drive my boat in the Spring I really enjoy it. But after a few weekends of boating it doesn't give me as much additional satisfaction as the first time. I still go boating. My total utility still goes up. But the MARGINAL (extra) utility I get from one more day goes down.

OPTIONAL: For more information or a different explanation see:

Since we start with no pants, the first pair we get from President Clinton gives us a lot of utility (satisfaction). Also since President Clinton still has millions (or billions) of pairs of pants left, giving us 260 million causes his utility (satisfaction) to go down only a little. OVERALL the society's utility (all of us plus President Clinton) increases. From the same amount of resources we are receiving more satisfaction.

Full Employment

The last E is full Employment.

Here we will define full employment as using ALL available resources, not just labor. This means that if we have full employment we are using all of our labor, factories, mines, fields, etc.

How does full employment help society achieve the maximum satisfaction from its limited resources?

Even though it seems simple to me, students have a difficult time understanding why employment of all our resources is necessary if we are to produce all we can and achieve the maximum satisfaction possible from our existing resources.

If we have full employment, we produce MORE. If we have unemployed resources, we produce LESS. This is why society's strive for full employment - it reduces scarcity and helps achieve the maximum satisfaction possible.

What is MACROECONOMICS?

ECO 212 ONLINE! is a course in MACROECONOMICS. In a Macroeconomics course we will study the WHOLE ECONOMY or the ECONOMY OF A COUNTRY.

The Macroeconomic Issues are:

  1. Unemployment (UE)
  2. Inflation (IN), and
  3. Economic Growth (EG)

If we use our 5 Es framework, in a course in Macroeconomics you would study ECONOMIC GROWTH and FULLEMPLOYMENT.

In a course in MICROECONOMICS you study the INDIVIDUAL parts of an economy. Issues would include the determination of prices of individual products, studying individual industries, or making individual consumer choices.

Using our 5Es framework, a course in Microeconomics would study ALLOCATIVE EFFICIENCY, PRODUCTIVE EFFICIENCY, and EQUITY.The

The only component of economnics not included in either a Macroeconomics course or a Microeconomics course is "Reducing consumer wants.'

Why Study Economics?

One last thing I'd like to discuss briefly in this introductory lecture is "why study economics?"

Most of you are taking this class because it is REQUIRED for your major. Right? Most of you are probably business majors (management, finance, marketing, accounting, etc.), but other majors sometimes also require a course in economics (political science, engineering, dietetics, education, nursing,).

Another reason to take an economics course is to become a more informed voter and citizen. Much of what the candidates and political leaders discuss can be better understood with a knowledge of economics. This semester let's pay attention to the economic and political news. We can use the discussion forum to discuss what we see and hear.